Printer Friendly

Printed from http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/495465

The 2007-2012 Outlook for Electric Signs in the United States

Description:
WHAT IS LATENT DEMAND AND THE P.I.E.?

The concept of latent demand is rather subtle. The term latent typically refers to something that is dormant, not observable, or not yet realized. Demand is the notion of an economic quantity that a target population or market requires under different assumptions of price, quality, and distribution, among other factors. Latent demand, therefore, is commonly defined by economists as the industry earnings of a market when that market becomes accessible and attractive to serve by competing firms. It is a measure, therefore, of potential industry earnings (P.I.E.) or total revenues (not profit) if the United States is served in an efficient manner. It is typically expressed as the total revenues potentially extracted by firms. The “market” is defined at a given level in the value chain. There can be latent demand at the retail level, at the wholesale level, the manufacturing level, and the raw materials level (the P.I.E. of higher levels of the value chain being always smaller than the P.I.E. of levels at lower levels of the same value chain, assuming all levels maintain minimum profitability).

The latent demand for electric signs in the United States is not actual or historic sales. Nor is latent demand future sales. In fact, latent demand can be either lower or higher than actual sales if a market is inefficient (i.e., not representative of relatively competitive levels). Inefficiencies arise from a number of factors, including the lack of international openness, cultural barriers to consumption, regulations, and cartel-like behavior on the part of firms. In general, however, latent demand is typically larger than actual sales in a market.

For reasons discussed later, this report does not consider the notion of “unit quantities”, only total latent revenues (i.e., a calculation of price times quantity is never made, though one is implied). The units used in this report are U.S. dollars not adjusted for inflation (i.e., the figures incorporate inflationary trends). If inflation rates vary in a substantial way compared to recent experience, actually sales can also exceed latent demand (not adjusted for inflation). On the other hand, latent demand can be typically higher than actual sales as there are often distribution inefficiencies that reduce actual sales below the level of latent demand.

As mentioned in the introduction, this study is strategic in nature, taking an aggregate and long-run view, irrespective of the players or products involved. In fact, all the current products or services on the market can cease to exist in their present form (i.e., at a brand-, R&D specification, or corporate-image level) and all the players can be replaced by other firms (i.e., via exits, entries, mergers, bankruptcies, etc.), and there will still be latent demand for electric signs at the aggregate level. Product and service offerings, and the actual identity of the players involved, while important for certain issues, are relatively unimportant for estimates of latent demand.

THE METHODOLOGY

In order to estimate the latent demand for electric signs across the states and cites of the United States, we used a multi-stage approach. Before applying the approach, one needs a basic theory from which such estimates are created. In this case, we heavily rely on the use of certain basic economic assumptions. In particular, there is an assumption governing the shape and type of aggregate latent demand functions. Latent demand functions relate the income of a state, city, household, or individual to realized consumption. Latent demand (often realized as consumption when an industry is efficient), at any level of the value chain, takes place if an equilibrium is realized. For firms to serve a market, they must perceive a latent demand and be able to serve that demand at a minimal return. The single most important variable determining consumption, assuming latent demand exists, is income (or other financial resources at higher levels of the value chain). Other factors that can pivot or shape demand curves include external or exogenous shocks (i.e., business cycles), and or changes in utility for the product in question.

Ignoring, for the moment, exogenous shocks and variations in utility across geographies, the aggregate relation between income and consumption has been a central theme in economics. The figure below concisely summarizes one aspect of problem. In the 1930s, John Meynard Keynes conjectured that as incomes rise, the average propensity to consume would fall. The average propensity to consume is the level of consumption divided by the level of income, or the slope of the line from the origin to the consumption function. He estimated this relationship empirically and found it to be true in the short-run (mostly based on cross-sectional data). The higher the income, the lower the average propensity to consume. This type of consumption function is labeled "A" in the figure below (note the rather flat slope of the curve). In the 1940s, another macroeconomist, Simon Kuznets, estimated long-run consumption functions which indicated that the marginal propensity to consume was rather constant (using time series data). This type of consumption function is shown as "B" in the figure below (note the higher slope and zero-zero intercept). The average propensity to consume is constant.

















Is it declining or is it constant? A number of other economists, notably Franco Modigliani and Milton Friedman, in the 1950s (and Irving Fisher earlier), explained why the two functions were different using various assumptions on intertemporal budget constraints, savings, and wealth. The shorter the time horizon, the more consumption can depend on wealth (earned in previous years) and business cycles. In the long-run, however, the propensity to consume is more constant. Similarly, in the long run, households with no income eventually have no consumption (wealth is depleted). While the debate surrounding beliefs about how income and consumption are related is interesting, in this study a very particular school of thought is adopted. In particular, we are considering the latent demand for electric signs across the states and cities of the United States. The smallest cities have few inhabitants. we assume that all of these cities fall along a "long-run" aggregate consumption function. This long-run function applies despite some of these states having wealth; current income dominates the latent demand for electric signs. So, latent demand in the long-run has a zero intercept. However, we allow different propensities to consume (including being on consumption functions with differing slopes, which can account for differences in industrial organization, and end-user preferences).

Given this overriding philosophy, we will now describe the methodology used to create the latent demand estimates for electric signs in the United States. Since this methodology has been applied to a large number of categories, the rather academic discussion below is general and can be applied to a wide variety of categories and geographic locations, not just electric signs in the United States.

Step 1. Product Definition and Data Collection

Any study of latent demand requires that some standard be established to define “efficiently served”. Having implemented various alternatives and matched these with market outcomes, we have found that the optimal approach is to assume that certain key indicators are more likely to reflect efficiency than others. These indicators are given greater weight than others in the estimation of latent demand compared to others for which no known data are available. Of the many alternatives, we have found the assumption that the highest aggregate income and highest income-per-capita markets reflect the best standards for “efficiency”. High aggregate income alone is not sufficient (i.e. some cities have high aggregate income, but low income per capita and can not assumed to be efficient). Aggregate income can be operationalized in a number of ways, including gross domestic product (for industrial categories), or total disposable income (for household categories; population times average income per capita, or number of households times average household income).

Latent demand is therefore estimated using data collected for relatively efficient markets from independent data sources (e.g. Official Chinese Agencies, the World Resources Institute, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, various agencies from the United Nations, industry trade associations, the International Monetary Fund, Euromonitor, Mintel, Thomson Financial Services, the U.S. Industrial Outlook, and the World Bank). Depending on original data sources used, the definition of “electric signs” is established. In the case of this report, the data were reported at the aggregate level, with no further breakdown or definition. In other words, any potential product or service that might be incorporated within electric signs falls under this category. Public sources rarely report data at the disaggregated level in order to protect private information from individual firms that might dominate a specific product-market. These sources will therefore aggregate across components of a category and report only the aggregate to the public. While private data are certainly available, this report only relies on public data at the aggregate level without reliance on the summation of various category components. In other words, this report does not aggregate a number of components to arrive at the “whole”. Rather, it starts with the “whole”, and estimates the whole for all states and cities in the United States (without needing to know the specific parts that went into the whole in the first place).

Given this caveat, this study covers “electric signs” as defined by the NAICS coding system (pronounced “nakes”). For a complete definition of electric signs, please see below. The NAICS code for electric signs is 3399501. It is for this definition of electric signs that the aggregate latent demand estimates are derived for the states and cities of the United States. “Electric signs” is specifically defined as follows:

3399501
Electric signs

339950101
Luminous tubing signs

339950102
Fluorescent signs

339950105
Incandescent bulb electric signs and other electric signs

33995011
Luminous tubing electric signs, including argon, hydrogen, and neon electric signs (excluding fluorescent lamp and incandescent bulb electric signs)

3399501101
Luminous tubing electric signs, including argon, hydrogen, and neon electric signs (excluding fluorescent lamp and incandescent bulb electric signs)

33995012
Fluorescent lamp electric signs

3399501206
Fluorescent lamp electric signs

33995013
Incandescent bulb electric signs

3399501311
Incandescent bulb electric signs with variable message display

3399501316
Other incandescent bulb electric signs

3399501321
Other electric signs, including electric signs made of combinations of luminous tubing, fluorescent lamps, and incandescent bulbs



Step 2. Filtering and Smoothing

Based on the aggregate view of electric signs as defined above, data were then collected for as many geographic locations as possible for that same definition, at the same level of the value chain. This generates a convenience sample of indicators from which comparable figures are available. If the series in question do not reflect the same accounting period, then adjustments are made. In order to eliminate short-term effects of business cycles, the series are smoothed using an 2 year moving average weighting scheme (longer weighting schemes do not substantially change the results). If data are available for a geographic region, but these reflect short-run aberrations due to exogenous shocks (such as would be the case of beef sales in a state or city stricken with foot and mouth disease), these observations were dropped or "filtered" from the analysis.

Step 3. Filling in Missing Values

In some cases, data are available on a sporadic basis. In other cases, data may be available for only one year. From a Bayesian perspective, these observations should be given greatest weight in estimating missing years. Assuming that other factors are held constant, the missing years are extrapolated using changes and growth in aggregate national, state and city-level income. Based on the overriding philosophy of a long-run consumption function (defined earlier), states and cities which have missing data for any given year, are estimated based on historical dynamics of aggregate income for that geographic entity.

Step 4. Varying Parameter, Non-linear Estimation

Given the data available from the first three steps, the latent demand is estimated using a “varying-parameter cross-sectionally pooled time series model”. Simply stated, the effect of income on latent demand is assumed to be constant unless there is empirical evidence to suggest that this effect varies (i.e., . the slope of the income effect is not necessarily same for all states or cities). This assumption applies along the aggregate consumption function, but also over time (i.e., not all states or cities in the United States are perceived to have the same income growth prospects over time). Another way of looking at this is to say that latent demand for electric signs is more likely to be similar across states or cities that have similar characteristics in terms of economic development.

This approach is useful across geographic regions for which some notion of non-linearity exists in the aggregate cross-region consumption function. For some categories, however, the reader must realize that the numbers will reflect a state’s or city’s contribution to latent demand in the United States and may never be realized in the form of local sales.

Step 5. Fixed-Parameter Linear Estimation

Nonlinearities are assumed in cases where filtered data exist along the aggregate consumption function. Because the United States consists of more than 15,000 cities, there will always be those cities, especially toward the bottom of the consumption function, where non-linear estimation is simply not possible. For these cities, equilibrium latent demand is assumed to be perfectly parametric and not a function of wealth (i.e., a city’s stock of income), but a function of current income (a city’s flow of income). In the long run, if a state has no current income, the latent demand for electric signs is assumed to approach zero. The assumption is that wealth stocks fall rapidly to zero if flow income falls to zero (i.e., cities which earn low levels of income will not use their savings, in the long run, to demand electric signs). In a graphical sense, for low income cities, latent demand approaches zero in a parametric linear fashion with a zero-zero intercept. In this stage of the estimation procedure, a low-income city is assumed to have a latent demand proportional to its income, based on the cities closest to it on the aggregate consumption function.

Step 6. Aggregation and Benchmarking

Based on the models described above, latent demand figures are estimated for all major cities in the United States. These are then aggregated to get state totals. This report considers a city as a part of the regional and national market. The purpose is to understand the density of demand within a state and the extent to which a city might be used as a point of distribution within its state. From an economic perspective, however, a city does not represent a population within rigid geographical boundaries. To an economist or strategic planner, a city represents an area of dominant influence over markets in adjacent areas. This influence varies from one industry to another, but also from one period of time to another. we allocate latent demand across areas of dominant influence based on the relative economic importance of cities within its state. Not all cities (e.g. the smaller towns) are estimated within each state as demand may be allocated to adjacent areas of influence. Since some cities have higher economic wealth than others within the same state, a city’s population is not generally used to allocate latent demand. Rather, the level of economic activity of the city vis-à-vis others is used.
 
Contents:
1 INTRODUCTION 9 1.1 Overview 9 1.2 What is Latent Demand and the P.I.E.? 9 1.3 The Methodology 10 1.3.1 Step 1. Product Definition and Data Collection 11 1.3.2 Step 2. Filtering and Smoothing 12 1.3.3 Step 3. Filling in Missing Values 12 1.3.4 Step 4. Varying Parameter, Non-linear Estimation 13 1.3.5 Step 5. Fixed-Parameter Linear Estimation 13 1.3.6 Step 6. Aggregation and Benchmarking 13 2 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS 15 2.1 Latent Demand in The US 15 3 FAR WEST 17 3.1 Executive Summary 17 3.2 Latent Demand by Year - Alaska 19 3.3 Cities Sorted by Rank - Alaska 20 3.4 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Alaska 21 3.5 Latent Demand by Year - California 23 3.6 Cities Sorted by Rank - California 24 3.7 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - California 43 3.8 Latent Demand by Year - Hawaii 62 3.9 Cities Sorted by Rank - Hawaii 63 3.10 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Hawaii 65 3.11 Latent Demand by Year - Nevada 68 3.12 Cities Sorted by Rank - Nevada 69 3.13 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Nevada 70 3.14 Latent Demand by Year - Oregon 72 3.15 Cities Sorted by Rank - Oregon 73 3.16 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Oregon 76 3.17 Latent Demand by Year - Washington 81 3.18 Cities Sorted by Rank - Washington 82 3.19 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Washington 89 4 GREAT LAKES 96 4.1 Executive Summary 96 4.2 Latent Demand by Year - Illinois 98 4.3 Cities Sorted by Rank - Illinois 99 4.4 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Illinois 112 4.5 Latent Demand by Year - Indiana 125 4.6 Cities Sorted by Rank - Indiana 126 4.7 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Indiana 132 4.8 Latent Demand by Year - Michigan 139 4.9 Cities Sorted by Rank - Michigan 140 4.10 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Michigan 148 4.11 Latent Demand by Year - Ohio 157 4.12 Cities Sorted by Rank - Ohio 158 4.13 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Ohio 170 4.14 Latent Demand by Year - Wisconsin 183 4.15 Cities Sorted by Rank - Wisconsin 184 4.16 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Wisconsin 194 5 MID-ATLANTIC 205 5.1 Executive Summary 205 5.2 Latent Demand by Year - Delaware 207 5.3 Cities Sorted by Rank - Delaware 208 5.4 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Delaware 209 5.5 Latent Demand by Year - District of Columbia 210 5.6 Cities Sorted by Rank - District of Columbia 211 5.7 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - District of Columbia 211 5.8 Latent Demand by Year - Maryland 212 5.9 Cities Sorted by Rank - Maryland 213 5.10 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Maryland 219 5.11 Latent Demand by Year - New Jersey 225 5.12 Cities Sorted by Rank - New Jersey 226 5.13 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - New Jersey 235 5.14 Latent Demand by Year - New York 244 5.15 Cities Sorted by Rank - New York 245 5.16 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - New York 270 5.17 Latent Demand by Year - Pennsylvania 297 5.18 Cities Sorted by Rank - Pennsylvania 298 5.19 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Pennsylvania 313 6 NEW ENGLAND 329 6.1 Executive Summary 329 6.2 Latent Demand by Year - Connecticut 331 6.3 Cities Sorted by Rank - Connecticut 332 6.4 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Connecticut 336 6.5 Latent Demand by Year - Maine 341 6.6 Cities Sorted by Rank - Maine 342 6.7 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Maine 347 6.8 Latent Demand by Year - Massachusetts 353 6.9 Cities Sorted by Rank - Massachusetts 354 6.10 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Massachusetts 362 6.11 Latent Demand by Year - New Hampshire 371 6.12 Cities Sorted by Rank - New Hampshire 372 6.13 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - New Hampshire 376 6.14 Latent Demand by Year - Rhode Island 380 6.15 Cities Sorted by Rank - Rhode Island 381 6.16 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Rhode Island 382 6.17 Latent Demand by Year - Vermont 384 6.18 Cities Sorted by Rank - Vermont 385 6.19 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Vermont 388 7 PLAINS 392 7.1 Executive Summary 392 7.2 Latent Demand by Year - Iowa 394 7.3 Cities Sorted by Rank - Iowa 395 7.4 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Iowa 399 7.5 Latent Demand by Year - Kansas 405 7.6 Cities Sorted by Rank - Kansas 406 7.7 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Kansas 409 7.8 Latent Demand by Year - Minnesota 413 7.9 Cities Sorted by Rank - Minnesota 414 7.10 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Minnesota 420 7.11 Latent Demand by Year - Missouri 427 7.12 Cities Sorted by Rank - Missouri 428 7.13 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Missouri 434 7.14 Latent Demand by Year - Nebraska 440 7.15 Cities Sorted by Rank - Nebraska 441 7.16 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Nebraska 442 7.17 Latent Demand by Year - North Dakota 445 7.18 Cities Sorted by Rank - North Dakota 446 7.19 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - North Dakota 446 7.20 Latent Demand by Year - South Dakota 448 7.21 Cities Sorted by Rank - South Dakota 449 7.22 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - South Dakota 450 8 ROCKIES 451 8.1 Executive Summary 451 8.2 Latent Demand by Year - Colorado 453 8.3 Cities Sorted by Rank - Colorado 454 8.4 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Colorado 458 8.5 Latent Demand by Year - Idaho 462 8.6 Cities Sorted by Rank - Idaho 463 8.7 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Idaho 464 8.8 Latent Demand by Year - Montana 466 8.9 Cities Sorted by Rank - Montana 467 8.10 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Montana 468 8.11 Latent Demand by Year - Utah 470 8.12 Cities Sorted by Rank - Utah 471 8.13 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Utah 474 8.14 Latent Demand by Year - Wyoming 478 8.15 Cities Sorted by Rank - Wyoming 479 8.16 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Wyoming 480 9 SOUTHEAST 481 9.1 Executive Summary 481 9.2 Latent Demand by Year - Alabama 483 9.3 Cities Sorted by Rank - Alabama 484 9.4 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Alabama 489 9.5 Latent Demand by Year - Arkansas 494 9.6 Cities Sorted by Rank - Arkansas 495 9.7 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Arkansas 498 9.8 Latent Demand by Year - Florida 502 9.9 Cities Sorted by Rank - Florida 503 9.10 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Florida 518 9.11 Latent Demand by Year - Georgia 533 9.12 Cities Sorted by Rank - Georgia 534 9.13 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Georgia 540 9.14 Latent Demand by Year - Kentucky 547 9.15 Cities Sorted by Rank - Kentucky 548 9.16 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Kentucky 552 9.17 Latent Demand by Year - Louisiana 556 9.18 Cities Sorted by Rank - Louisiana 557 9.19 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Louisiana 561 9.20 Latent Demand by Year - Mississippi 566 9.21 Cities Sorted by Rank - Mississippi 567 9.22 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Mississippi 569 9.23 Latent Demand by Year - North Carolina 573 9.24 Cities Sorted by Rank - North Carolina 574 9.25 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - North Carolina 581 9.26 Latent Demand by Year - South Carolina 588 9.27 Cities Sorted by Rank - South Carolina 589 9.28 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - South Carolina 593 9.29 Latent Demand by Year - Tennessee 598 9.30 Cities Sorted by Rank - Tennessee 599 9.31 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Tennessee 604 9.32 Latent Demand by Year - Virginia 609 9.33 Cities Sorted by Rank - Virginia 610 9.34 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Virginia 614 9.35 Latent Demand by Year - West Virginia 619 9.36 Cities Sorted by Rank - West Virginia 620 9.37 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - West Virginia 622 10 SOUTHWEST 624 10.1 Executive Summary 624 10.2 Latent Demand by Year - Arizona 625 10.3 Cities Sorted by Rank - Arizona 626 10.4 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Arizona 629 10.5 Latent Demand by Year - New Mexico 633 10.6 Cities Sorted by Rank - New Mexico 634 10.7 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - New Mexico 636 10.8 Latent Demand by Year - Oklahoma 638 10.9 Cities Sorted by Rank - Oklahoma 639 10.10 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Oklahoma 642 10.11 Latent Demand by Year - Texas 647 10.12 Cities Sorted by Rank - Texas 648 10.13 Cities Sorted by Zipcode - Texas 664 11 DISCLAIMERS, WARRANTEES, AND USER AGREEMENT PROVISIONS 682 11.1 Disclaimers & Safe Harbor 682 11.2 User Agreement Provisions 683
 
Ordering:
Order Online - visit http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/495465

Order by Fax - using the order form below

Order By Post - print the order form below and send to

Research and Markets,
Guinness Centre,
Taylors Lane,
Dublin 8,
Ireland.

 
Page 1 of 2
Printed Apr 20th 2014
2:55:24 AM

Fax order form

To place a fax order simply print this form, fill in and fax the completed form to the number below. If you have any questions please email help@researchandmarkets.net

Order information

Please verify that the product information is correct and select the format you require.

Product name

The 2007-2012 Outlook for Electric Signs in the United States

Web Address

http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/495465

Office Code

OC8DINPOOOVRWR

 

Report Formats

Please enter the quantity of the report format you require.

Format Quantity Price
Electronic - Single User EUR 364

Contact information

Please enter all the information below in block capitals.

Title:
Mr Mrs Dr Miss Ms Prof
First Name:
Last Name:
Email Address:
Job Title:
Organisation:
Address:
City:
Postal / Zip Code:
Country:
Phone Number:
Fax Number:

Please fax this form to:
(646) 607-1907 or (646) 964-6609 (from USA)
+353-1-481-1716 or +353-1-653-1571 (from Rest of World)

Page 2 of 2
Printed Apr 20th 2014
2:55:24 AM

Payment information

Please indicate the payment method you would like to use by selecting the appropriate box.

Pay by Credit Card:

American Express

Diners Club

Master Card

Visa

Cardholder's Name:
Cardholder's Signature:
Expiry Date:
/
Card Number:
CVV Security Code:
Issue date:
/ (Diners Club only)
 
Pay by Check:

Please post the check, accompanied by this form, to:

Research and Markets,
Guinness Centre,
Taylors Lane,
Dublin 8,
Ireland.

 
Pay by Wire Transfer:

Please transfer funds to:

Account Number:
83313083
Sort Code:
98-53-30
Swift Code:
ULSBIE2D
IBAN Number:
IE78ULSB98533083313083
Bank Address:
Ulster Bank,
27-35 Main Street
Blackrock,
Co. Dublin
Ireland.
 

If you have a Marketing Code please enter it below:

Marketing Code:

Please note that by ordering from Research and Markets you are agreeing to our Terms and Conditions at http://www.researchandmarkets.com/info/terms.asp

Please fax this form to:
(646) 607-1907 or (646) 964-6609 (from USA)
+353-1-481-1716 or +353-1-653-1571 (from Rest of World)