Printer Friendly

Printed from http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/499497

The 2007-2012 World Outlook for Manufacturing Clay Sewer Pipe, Drain Tile, Flue Lining Tile, Architectural Terra-Cotta, and Other Structural Clay Products

Description:
WHAT IS LATENT DEMAND AND THE P.I.E.?

The concept of latent demand is rather subtle. The term latent typically refers to something that is dormant, not observable, or not yet realized. Demand is the notion of an economic quantity that a target population or market requires under different assumptions of price, quality, and distribution, among other factors. Latent demand, therefore, is commonly defined by economists as the industry earnings of a market when that market becomes accessible and attractive to serve by competing firms. It is a measure, therefore, of potential industry earnings (P.I.E.) or total revenues (not profit) if a market is served in an efficient manner. It is typically expressed as the total revenues potentially extracted by firms. The “market” is defined at a given level in the value chain. There can be latent demand at the retail level, at the wholesale level, the manufacturing level, and the raw materials level (the P.I.E. of higher levels of the value chain being always smaller than the P.I.E. of levels at lower levels of the same value chain, assuming all levels maintain minimum profitability).

The latent demand for manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products is not actual or historic sales. Nor is latent demand future sales. In fact, latent demand can be lower either lower or higher than actual sales if a market is inefficient (i.e., not representative of relatively competitive levels). Inefficiencies arise from a number of factors, including the lack of international openness, cultural barriers to consumption, regulations, and cartel-like behavior on the part of firms. In general, however, latent demand is typically larger than actual sales in a country market.

For reasons discussed later, this report does not consider the notion of “unit quantities”, only total latent revenues (i.e., a calculation of price times quantity is never made, though one is implied). The units used in this report are U.S. dollars not adjusted for inflation (i.e., the figures incorporate inflationary trends) and not adjusted for future dynamics in exchange rates (i.e., the figures reflect average exchange rates over recent history). If inflation rates or exchange rates vary in a substantial way compared to recent experience, actually sales can also exceed latent demand (when expressed in U.S. dollars, not adjusted for inflation). On the other hand, latent demand can be typically higher than actual sales as there are often distribution inefficiencies that reduce actual sales below the level of latent demand.

As mentioned in the introduction, this study is strategic in nature, taking an aggregate and long-run view, irrespective of the players or products involved. If fact, all the current products or services on the market can cease to exist in their present form (i.e., at a brand-, R&D specification, or corporate-image level) and all the players can be replaced by other firms (i.e., via exits, entries, mergers, bankruptcies, etc.), and there will still be an international latent demand for manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products at the aggregate level. Product and service offering details, and the actual identity of the players involved, while important for certain issues, are relatively unimportant for estimates of latent demand.

THE METHODOLOGY

In order to estimate the latent demand for manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products on a worldwide basis, we used a multi-stage approach. Before applying the approach, one needs a basic theory from which such estimates are created. In this case, we heavily rely on the use of certain basic economic assumptions. In particular, there is an assumption governing the shape and type of aggregate latent demand functions. Latent demand functions relate the income of a country, city, state, household, or individual to realized consumption. Latent demand (often realized as consumption when an industry is efficient), at any level of the value chain, takes place if an equilibrium in realized. For firms to serve a market, they must perceive a latent demand and be able to serve that demand at a minimal return. The single most important variable determining consumption, assuming latent demand exists, is income (or other financial resources at higher levels of the value chain). Other factors that can pivot or shape demand curves include external or exogenous shocks (i.e., business cycles), and or changes in utility for the product in question.

Ignoring, for the moment, exogenous shocks and variations in utility across countries, the aggregate relation between income and consumption has been a central theme in economics. The figure below concisely summarizes one aspect of problem. In the 1930s, John Meynard Keynes conjectured that as incomes rise, the average propensity to consume would fall. The average propensity to consume is the level of consumption divided by the level of income, or the slope of the line from the origin to the consumption function. He estimated this relationship empirically and found it to be true in the short-run (mostly based on cross-sectional data). The higher the income, the lower the average propensity to consume. This type of consumption function is labeled "A" in the figure below (note the rather flat slope of the curve). In the 1940s, another macroeconomist, Simon Kuznets, estimated long-run consumption functions which indicated that the marginal propensity to consume was rather constant (using time series data across countries). This type of consumption function is show as "B" in the figure below (note the higher slope and zero-zero intercept). The average propensity to consume is constant.

















Is it declining or is it constant? A number of other economists, notably Franco Modigliani and Milton Friedman, in the 1950s (and Irving Fisher earlier), explained why the two functions were different using various assumptions on intertemporal budget constraints, savings, and wealth. The shorter the time horizon, the more consumption can depend on wealth (earned in previous years) and business cycles. In the long-run, however, the propensity to consume is more constant. Similarly, in the long run, households, industries or countries with no income eventually have no consumption (wealth is depleted). While the debate surrounding beliefs about how income and consumption are related and interesting, in this study a very particular school of thought is adopted. In particular, we are considering the latent demand for manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products across some 230 countries. The smallest have fewer than 10,000 inhabitants. we assume that all of these counties fall along a "long-run" aggregate consumption function. This long-run function applies despite some of these countries having wealth, current income dominates the latent demand for manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products. So, latent demand in the long-run has a zero intercept. However, we allow firms to have different propensities to consume (including being on consumption functions with differing slopes, which can account for differences in industrial organization, and end-user preferences).

Given this overriding philosophy, we will now describe the methodology used to create the latent demand estimates for manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products. Since this methodology has been applied to a large number of categories, the rather academic discussion below is general and can be applied to a wide variety of categories, not just manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products.

Step 1. Product Definition and Data Collection

Any study of latent demand across countries requires that some standard be established to define “efficiently served”. Having implemented various alternatives and matched these with market outcomes, we have found that the optimal approach is to assume that certain key countries are more likely to be at or near efficiency than others. These countries are given greater weight than others in the estimation of latent demand compared to other countries for which no known data are available. Of the many alternatives, we have found the assumption that the world’s highest aggregate income and highest income-per-capita markets reflect the best standards for “efficiency”. High aggregate income alone is not sufficient (i.e., China has high aggregate income, but low income per capita and can not assumed to be efficient). Aggregate income can be operationalized in a number of ways, including gross domestic product (for industrial categories), or total disposable income (for household categories; population times average income per capita, or number of households times average household income per capita). Brunei, Nauru, Kuwait, and Lichtenstein are examples of countries with high income per capita, but not assumed to be efficient, given low aggregate level of income (or gross domestic product); these countries have, however, high incomes per capita but may not benefit from the efficiencies derived from economies of scale associated with large economies. Only countries with high income per capita and large aggregate income are assumed efficient. This greatly restricts the pool of countries to those in the OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development), like the United States, or the United Kingdom (which were earlier than other large OECD economies to liberalize their markets).

The selection of countries is further reduced by the fact that not all countries in the OECD report industry revenues at the category level. Countries that typically have ample data at the aggregate level that meet the efficiency criteria include the United States, the United Kingdom and in some cases France and Germany.

Latent demand is therefore estimated using data collected for relatively efficient markets from independent data sources (e.g. Euromonitor, Mintel, Thomson Financial Services, the U.S. Industrial Outlook, the World Resources Institute, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, various agencies from the United Nations, industry trade associations, the International Monetary Fund, and the World Bank). Depending on original data sources used, the definition of “manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products” is established. In the case of this report, the data were reported at the aggregate level, with no further breakdown or definition. In other words, any potential product or service that might be incorporated within manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products falls under this category. Public sources rarely report data at the disaggregated level in order to protect private information from individual firms that might dominate a specific product-market. These sources will therefore aggregate across components of a category and report only the aggregate to the public. While private data are certainly available, this report only relies on public data at the aggregate level without reliance on the summation of various category components. In other words, this report does not aggregate a number of components to arrive at the “whole”. Rather, it starts with the “whole”, and estimates the whole for all countries and the world at large (without needing to know the specific parts that went into the whole in the first place).

Given this caveat, this study covers “manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products” as defined by the North American Industrial Classification system or NAICS (pronounced “nakes”). For a complete definition of manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products, please see below. The NAICS code for manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products is 327123. It is for this definition of manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products that the aggregate latent demand estimates are derived. “Manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products” is specifically defined as follows:

327123
This U.S. industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products.

3271231
vitrified clay sewer pipe and fittings

32712310
Vitrified clay sewer pipe and fittings

3271231000
Vitrified clay sewer pipe and fittings

32712311
vitrified clay sewer pipe and fittings

3271231100
vitrified clay sewer pipe and fittings

3271232
Other structural clay products, n.e.c.

327123225
Clay roofing tile

327123298
Other structural clay products incl terra cotta, drain and flue tile, conduit and adobe

3271234
ALL OTHER STRUCTURAL CLAY PRODUCTS (ARCHITECTURAL TERRA COTTA, DRAIN TILE, FLUE TILE, ROOFING TILE, CONDUIT, ETC.), EXCEPT CLAY REFRACTORIES

32712341
All other structural clay products (architectural terra cotta, drain tile, flue tile, roofing tile, conduit, etc.), except clay refractories

3271234100
All other structural clay products (architectural terra cotta, drain tile, flue tile, roofing tile, conduit, etc.), except clay refractories

327123M
Miscellaneous receipts

327123P
Primary products

327123S
Secondary products


Furthermore, the definition of NAICS code 327123 includes the following:

Adobe bricks manufacturing
Architectural terra cotta manufacturing
Bricks, adobe, manufacturing
Conduit, vitrified clay, manufacturing
Coping, wall, clay, manufacturing
Drain tile, clay, manufacturing
Flue lining, clay, manufacturing
Liner brick and plates, vitrified clay, manufacturing
Roofing tile, clay, manufacturing
Sewer pipe and fittings, clay, manufacturing
Stove lining, clay, manufacturing
Tile, roofing and drain, clay, manufacturing
Tile, sewer, clay, manufacturing.


Step 2. Filtering and Smoothing

Based on the aggregate view of manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products as defined above, data were then collected for as many similar countries as possible for that same definition, at the same level of the value chain. This generates a convenience sample of countries from which comparable figures are available. If the series in question do not reflect the same accounting period, then adjustments are made. In order to eliminate short-term effects of business cycles, the series are smoothed using an 2 year moving average weighting scheme (longer weighting schemes do not substantially change the results). If data are available for a country, but these reflect short-run aberrations due to exogenous shocks (such as would be the case of beef sales in a country stricken with foot and mouth disease), these observations were dropped or "filtered" from the analysis.

Step 3. Filling in Missing Values

In some cases, data are available for countries on a sporadic basis. In other cases, data from a country may be available for only one year. From a Bayesian perspective, these observations should be given greatest weight in estimating missing years. Assuming that other factors are held constant, the missing years are extrapolated using changes and growth in aggregate national income. Based on the overriding philosophy of a long-run consumption function (defined earlier), countries which have missing data for any given year, are estimated based on historical dynamics of aggregate income for that country.

Step 4. Varying Parameter, Non-linear Estimation

Given the data available from the first three steps, the latent demand in additional countries is estimated using a “varying-parameter cross-sectionally pooled time series model”. Simply stated, the effect of income on latent demand is assumed to be constant across countries unless there is empirical evidence to suggest that this effect varies (i.e., . the slope of the income effect is not necessarily same for all countries). This assumption applies across countries along the aggregate consumption function, but also over time (i.e., not all countries are perceived to have the same income growth prospects over time and this effect can vary from country to country as well). Another way of looking at this is to say that latent demand for manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products is more likely to be similar across countries that have similar characteristics in terms of economic development (i.e., African countries will have similar latent demand structures controlling for the income variation across the pool of African countries).

This approach is useful across countries for which some notion of non-linearity exists in the aggregate cross-country consumption function. For some categories, however, the reader must realize that the numbers will reflect a country’s contribution to global latent demand and may never be realized in the form of local sales. For certain country-category combinations this will result in what at first glance will be odd results. For example, the latent demand for the category “space vehicles” will exist for “Togo” even though they have no space program. The assumption is that if the economies in these countries did not exist, the world aggregate for these categories would be lower. The share attributed to these countries is based on a proportion of their income (however small) being used to consume the category in question (i.e., perhaps via resellers).

Step 5. Fixed-Parameter Linear Estimation

Nonlinearities are assumed in cases where filtered data exist along the aggregate consumption function. Because the world consists of more than 200 countries, there will always be those countries, especially toward the bottom of the consumption function, where non-linear estimation is simply not possible. For these countries, equilibrium latent demand is assumed to be perfectly parametric and not a function of wealth (i.e., a country’s stock of income), but a function of current income (a country’s flow of income). In the long run, if a country has no current income, the latent demand for manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products is assumed to approach zero. The assumption is that wealth stocks fall rapidly to zero if flow income falls to zero (i.e., countries which earn low levels of income will not use their savings, in the long run, to demand manufacturing clay sewer pipe, drain tile, flue lining tile, architectural terra-cotta, and other structural clay products). In a graphical sense, for low income countries, latent demand approaches zero in a parametric linear fashion with a zero-zero intercept. In this stage of the estimation procedure, low-income countries are assumed to have a latent demand proportional to their income, based on the country closest to it on the aggregate consumption function.

Step 6. Aggregation and Benchmarking

Based on the models described above, latent demand figures are estimated for all countries of the world, including for the smallest economies. These are then aggregated to get world totals and regional totals. To make the numbers more meaningful, regional and global demand averages are presented. Figures are rounded, so minor inconsistencies may exist across tables.

Step 7. Latent Demand Density: Allocating Across Cities

With the advent of a “borderless world”, cities become a more important criteria in prioritizing markets, as opposed to regions, continents, or countries. This report also covers the world’s top 2000 cities. The purpose is to understand the density of demand within a country and the extent to which a city might be used as a point of distribution within its region. From an economic perspective, however, a city does not represent a population within rigid geographical boundaries. To an economist or strategic planner, a city represents an area of dominant influence over markets in adjacent areas. This influence varies from one industry to another, but also from one period of time to another.

Similar to country-level data, the reader needs to realize that latent demand allocated to a city may or may not represent real sales. For many items, latent demand is clearly observable in sales, as in the case for food or housing items. Consider, again, the category “satellite launch vehicles.” Clearly, there are no launch pads in most cities of the world. However, the core benefit of the vehicles (e.g. telecommunications, etc.) is "consumed" by residents or industries within the worlds cities. Without certain cities, in other words, the world market for satellite launch vehicles would be lower for the world in general. One needs to allocate, therefore, a portion of the worldwide economic demand for launch vehicles to regions, countries and cities. This report takes the broader definition and considers, therefore, a city as a part of the global market. we allocate latent demand across areas of dominant influence based on the relative economic importance of cities within its home country, within its region and across the world total. Not all cities are estimated within each country as demand may be allocated to adjacent areas of influence. Since some cities have higher economic wealth than others within the same country, a city’s population is not generally used to allocate latent demand. Rather, the level of economic activity of the city vis-à-vis others.
 
Contents:
1 INTRODUCTION 10 1.1 Overview 10 1.2 What is Latent Demand and the P.I.E.? 10 1.3 The Methodology 11 1.3.1 Step 1. Product Definition and Data Collection 12 1.3.2 Step 2. Filtering and Smoothing 15 1.3.3 Step 3. Filling in Missing Values 15 1.3.4 Step 4. Varying Parameter, Non-linear Estimation 15 1.3.5 Step 5. Fixed-Parameter Linear Estimation 16 1.3.6 Step 6. Aggregation and Benchmarking 16 1.3.7 Step 7. Latent Demand Density: Allocating Across Cities 16 2 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS 17 2.1 The Worldwide Market Potential 17 3 AFRICA 19 3.1 Executive Summary 19 3.2 Algeria 20 3.3 Angola 21 3.4 Benin 22 3.5 Botswana 23 3.6 Burkina Faso 24 3.7 Burundi 24 3.8 Cameroon 25 3.9 Cape Verde 26 3.10 Central African Republic 26 3.11 Chad 27 3.12 Comoros 28 3.13 Congo (formerly Zaire) 28 3.14 Cote dIvoire 29 3.15 Djibouti 30 3.16 Egypt 31 3.17 Equatorial Guinea 32 3.18 Ethiopia 32 3.19 Gabon 33 3.20 Ghana 34 3.21 Guinea 35 3.22 Guinea-Bissau 35 3.23 Kenya 36 3.24 Lesotho 37 3.25 Liberia 37 3.26 Libya 38 3.27 Madagascar 39 3.28 Malawi 39 3.29 Mali 40 3.30 Mauritania 41 3.31 Mauritius 41 3.32 Morocco 42 3.33 Mozambique 43 3.34 Namibia 43 3.35 Niger 44 3.36 Nigeria 45 3.37 Republic of Congo 46 3.38 Reunion 46 3.39 Rwanda 47 3.40 Sao Tome E Principe 48 3.41 Senegal 48 3.42 Sierra Leone 49 3.43 Somalia 50 3.44 South Africa 51 3.45 Sudan 52 3.46 Swaziland 53 3.47 Tanzania 53 3.48 The Gambia 54 3.49 Togo 55 3.50 Tunisia 56 3.51 Uganda 57 3.52 Western Sahara 58 3.53 Zambia 58 3.54 Zimbabwe 59 4 ASIA 61 4.1 Executive Summary 61 4.2 Bangladesh 62 4.3 Bhutan 63 4.4 Brunei 64 4.5 Burma 65 4.6 Cambodia 66 4.7 China 66 4.8 Hong Kong 67 4.9 India 68 4.10 Indonesia 69 4.11 Japan 70 4.12 Laos 71 4.13 Macau 71 4.14 Malaysia 72 4.15 Maldives 73 4.16 Mongolia 74 4.17 Nepal 74 4.18 North Korea 75 4.19 Papua New Guinea 76 4.20 Philippines 76 4.21 Seychelles 77 4.22 Singapore 78 4.23 South Korea 79 4.24 Sri Lanka 80 4.25 Taiwan 81 4.26 Thailand 82 4.27 Vietnam 83 5 EUROPE & THE MIDDLE EAST 84 5.1 Executive Summary 84 5.2 Afghanistan 85 5.3 Albania 86 5.4 Andorra 87 5.5 Armenia 88 5.6 Austria 89 5.7 Azerbaijan 90 5.8 Bahrain 91 5.9 Belarus 91 5.10 Belgium 92 5.11 Bosnia and Herzegovina 93 5.12 Bulgaria 94 5.13 Croatia 95 5.14 Cyprus 96 5.15 Czech Republic 96 5.16 Denmark 97 5.17 Estonia 98 5.18 Finland 99 5.19 France 100 5.20 Georgia 101 5.21 Germany 102 5.22 Greece 103 5.23 Hungary 104 5.24 Iceland 105 5.25 Iran 106 5.26 Iraq 107 5.27 Ireland 108 5.28 Israel 108 5.29 Italy 109 5.30 Jordan 110 5.31 Kazakhstan 111 5.32 Kuwait 112 5.33 Kyrgyzstan 113 5.34 Latvia 114 5.35 Lebanon 114 5.36 Liechtenstein 115 5.37 Lithuania 116 5.38 Luxembourg 116 5.39 Malta 117 5.40 Moldova 118 5.41 Monaco 118 5.42 Netherlands 119 5.43 Norway 120 5.44 Oman 121 5.45 Pakistan 121 5.46 Palestine 122 5.47 Poland 123 5.48 Portugal 124 5.49 Qatar 125 5.50 Romania 125 5.51 Russia 126 5.52 San Marino 127 5.53 Saudi Arabia 128 5.54 Slovakia 129 5.55 Slovenia 129 5.56 Spain 130 5.57 Sweden 131 5.58 Switzerland 132 5.59 Syrian Arab Republic 133 5.60 Tajikistan 134 5.61 Turkey 135 5.62 Turkmenistan 136 5.63 Ukraine 136 5.64 United Arab Emirates 137 5.65 United Kingdom 138 5.66 Uzbekistan 139 5.67 Yemen 140 6 LATIN AMERICA 141 6.1 Executive Summary 141 6.2 Argentina 142 6.3 Belize 143 6.4 Bolivia 144 6.5 Brazil 145 6.6 Chile 146 6.7 Colombia 147 6.8 Costa Rica 148 6.9 Ecuador 148 6.10 El Salvador 149 6.11 Falkland Islands 150 6.12 French Guiana 150 6.13 Guatemala 151 6.14 Guyana 152 6.15 Honduras 152 6.16 Mexico 153 6.17 Nicaragua 154 6.18 Panama 155 6.19 Paraguay 156 6.20 Peru 157 6.21 Suriname 158 6.22 Uruguay 158 6.23 Venezuela 159 7 NORTH AMERICA & THE CARIBBEAN 161 7.1 Executive Summary 161 7.2 Antigua and Barbuda 162 7.3 Aruba 163 7.4 Bahamas 164 7.5 Barbados 164 7.6 Bermuda 165 7.7 British Virgin Islands 166 7.8 Canada 166 7.9 Cayman Islands 167 7.10 Cuba 168 7.11 Dominica 169 7.12 Dominican Republic 169 7.13 Greenland 170 7.14 Grenada 171 7.15 Guadeloupe 172 7.16 Haiti 173 7.17 Jamaica 173 7.18 Martinique 174 7.19 Netherlands Antilles 175 7.20 Puerto Rico 175 7.21 St. Kitts and Nevis 176 7.22 St. Lucia 177 7.23 St. Vincent and the Grenadines 177 7.24 Trinidad and Tobago 178 7.25 United States 179 7.26 Virgin Islands, US 180 8 OCEANA 181 8.1 Executive Summary 181 8.2 American Samoa 182 8.3 Australia 183 8.4 Christmas Island 184 8.5 Cook Islands 184 8.6 Fiji 185 8.7 French Polynesia 186 8.8 Guam 186 8.9 Kiribati 187 8.10 Marshall Islands 188 8.11 Micronesia Federation 188 8.12 Nauru 189 8.13 New Caledonia 190 8.14 New Zealand 190 8.15 Niue 191 8.16 Norfolk Island 192 8.17 Northern Mariana Island 192 8.18 Palau 193 8.19 Solomon Islands 194 8.20 Tokelau 194 8.21 Tonga 195 8.22 Tuvalu 196 8.23 Vanuatu 196 8.24 Wallis and Futuna 197 8.25 Western Samoa 198 9 DISCLAIMERS, WARRANTEES, AND USER AGREEMENT PROVISIONS 199 9.1 Disclaimers & Safe Harbor 199 9.2 User Agreement Provisions 200
 
Ordering:
Order Online - visit http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/499497

Order by Fax - using the order form below

Order By Post - print the order form below and send to

Research and Markets,
Guinness Centre,
Taylors Lane,
Dublin 8,
Ireland.

 
Page 1 of 2
Printed Nov 26, 2014
4:45:46 PM

Fax order form

To place a fax order simply print this form, fill in and fax the completed form to the number below. If you have any questions please email help@researchandmarkets.net

Order information

Please verify that the product information is correct and select the format you require.

Product name

The 2007-2012 World Outlook for Manufacturing Clay Sewer Pipe, Drain Tile, Flue Lining Tile, Architectural Terra-Cotta, and Other Structural Clay Products

Web Address

http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/499497

Office Code

SCOI7T

 

Report Formats

Please enter the quantity of the report format you require.

Format Quantity Price
Electronic - Single User USD 795

Contact information

Please enter all the information below in block capitals.

Title:
Mr Mrs Dr Miss Ms Prof
First Name:
Last Name:
Email Address:
Job Title:
Organisation:
Address:
City:
Postal / Zip Code:
Country:
Phone Number:
Fax Number:

Please fax this form to:
(646) 607-1907 or (646) 964-6609 (from USA)
+353-1-481-1716 or +353-1-653-1571 (from Rest of World)

Page 2 of 2
Printed Nov 26, 2014
4:45:46 PM

Payment information

Please indicate the payment method you would like to use by selecting the appropriate box.

Pay by Credit Card:

American Express

Diners Club

Master Card

Visa

Cardholder's Name:
Cardholder's Signature:
Expiry Date:
/
Card Number:
CVV Security Code:
Issue date:
/ (Diners Club only)
 
Pay by Check:

Please post the check, accompanied by this form, to:

Research and Markets,
Guinness Centre,
Taylors Lane,
Dublin 8,
Ireland.

 
Pay by Wire Transfer:

Please transfer funds to:

Account Number:
83313083
Sort Code:
98-53-30
Swift Code:
ULSBIE2D
IBAN Number:
IE78ULSB98533083313083
Bank Address:
Ulster Bank,
27-35 Main Street
Blackrock,
Co. Dublin
Ireland.
 

If you have a Marketing Code please enter it below:

Marketing Code:

Please note that by ordering from Research and Markets you are agreeing to our Terms and Conditions at http://www.researchandmarkets.com/info/terms.asp

Please fax this form to:
(646) 607-1907 or (646) 964-6609 (from USA)
+353-1-481-1716 or +353-1-653-1571 (from Rest of World)