Printer Friendly

Printed from http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/674489

The 2009-2014 World Outlook for Lithographic Printing of Flat Custom and Stock Paper Labels Excluding Pressure-Sensitive Labels

Description:
WHAT IS LATENT DEMAND AND THE P.I.E.? The concept of latent demand is rather subtle. The term latent typically refers to something that is dormant, not observable, or not yet realized. Demand is the notion of an economic quantity that a target population or market requires under different assumptions of price, quality, and distribution, among other factors. Latent demand, therefore, is commonly defined by economists as the industry earnings of a market when that market becomes accessible and attractive to serve by competing firms. It is a measure, therefore, of potential industry earnings (P.I.E.) or total revenues (not profit) if a market is served in an efficient manner. It is typically expressed as the total revenues potentially extracted by firms. The “market” is defined at a given level in the value chain. There can be latent demand at the retail level, at the wholesale level, the manufacturing level, and the raw materials level (the P.I.E. of higher levels of the value chain being always smaller than the P.I.E. of levels at lower levels of the same value chain, assuming all levels maintain minimum profitability). The latent demand for lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels is not actual or historic sales. Nor is latent demand future sales. In fact, latent demand can be lower either lower or higher than actual sales if a market is inefficient (i.e., not representative of relatively competitive levels). Inefficiencies arise from a number of factors, including the lack of international openness, cultural barriers to consumption, regulations, and cartel-like behavior on the part of firms. In general, however, latent demand is typically larger than actual sales in a country market. For reasons discussed later, this report does not consider the notion of “unit quantities”, only total latent revenues (i.e., a calculation of price times quantity is never made, though one is implied). The units used in this report are U.S. dollars not adjusted for inflation (i.e., the figures incorporate inflationary trends) and not adjusted for future dynamics in exchange rates. If inflation rates or exchange rates vary in a substantial way compared to recent experience, actually sales can also exceed latent demand (when expressed in U.S. dollars, not adjusted for inflation). On the other hand, latent demand can be typically higher than actual sales as there are often distribution inefficiencies that reduce actual sales below the level of latent demand. As mentioned in the introduction, this study is strategic in nature, taking an aggregate and long-run view, irrespective of the players or products involved. If fact, all the current products or services on the market can cease to exist in their present form (i.e., at a brand-, R&D specification, or corporate-image level) and all the players can be replaced by other firms (i.e., via exits, entries, mergers, bankruptcies, etc.), and there will still be an international latent demand for lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels at the aggregate level. Product and service offering details, and the actual identity of the players involved, while important for certain issues, are relatively unimportant for estimates of latent demand. THE METHODOLOGY In order to estimate the latent demand for lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels on a worldwide basis, I used a multi-stage approach. Before applying the approach, one needs a basic theory from which such estimates are created. In this case, I heavily rely on the use of certain basic economic assumptions. In particular, there is an assumption governing the shape and type of aggregate latent demand functions. Latent demand functions relate the income of a country, city, state, household, or individual to realized consumption. Latent demand (often realized as consumption when an industry is efficient), at any level of the value chain, takes place if an equilibrium is realized. For firms to serve a market, they must perceive a latent demand and be able to serve that demand at a minimal return. The single most important variable determining consumption, assuming latent demand exists, is income (or other financial resources at higher levels of the value chain). Other factors that can pivot or shape demand curves include external or exogenous shocks (i.e., business cycles), and or changes in utility for the product in question. Ignoring, for the moment, exogenous shocks and variations in utility across countries, the aggregate relation between income and consumption has been a central theme in economics. The figure below concisely summarizes one aspect of problem. In the 1930s, John Meynard Keynes conjectured that as incomes rise, the average propensity to consume would fall. The average propensity to consume is the level of consumption divided by the level of income, or the slope of the line from the origin to the consumption function. He estimated this relationship empirically and found it to be true in the short-run (mostly based on cross-sectional data). The higher the income, the lower the average propensity to consume. This type of consumption function is labeled "A" in the figure below (note the rather flat slope of the curve). In the 1940s, another macroeconomist, Simon Kuznets, estimated long-run consumption functions which indicated that the marginal propensity to consume was rather constant (using time series data across countries). This type of consumption function is show as "B" in the figure below (note the higher slope and zero-zero intercept). The average propensity to consume is constant. Is it declining or is it constant? A number of other economists, notably Franco Modigliani and Milton Friedman, in the 1950s (and Irving Fisher earlier), explained why the two functions were different using various assumptions on intertemporal budget constraints, savings, and wealth. The shorter the time horizon, the more consumption can depend on wealth (earned in previous years) and business cycles. In the long-run, however, the propensity to consume is more constant. Similarly, in the long run, households, industries or countries with no income eventually have no consumption (wealth is depleted). While the debate surrounding beliefs about how income and consumption are related and interesting, in this study a very particular school of thought is adopted. In particular, we are considering the latent demand for lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels across some 230 countries. The smallest have fewer than 10,000 inhabitants. I assume that all of these counties fall along a "long-run" aggregate consumption function. This long-run function applies despite some of these countries having wealth, current income dominates the latent demand for lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels. So, latent demand in the long-run has a zero intercept. However, I allow firms to have different propensities to consume (including being on consumption functions with differing slopes, which can account for differences in industrial organization, and end-user preferences). Given this overriding philosophy, I will now describe the methodology used to create the latent demand estimates for lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels. Since ICON Group has asked me to apply this methodology to a large number of categories, the rather academic discussion below is general and can be applied to a wide variety of categories, not just lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels. Step 1. Product Definition and Data Collection Any study of latent demand across countries requires that some standard be established to define “efficiently served”. Having implemented various alternatives and matched these with market outcomes, I have found that the optimal approach is to assume that certain key countries are more likely to be at or near efficiency than others. These countries are given greater weight than others in the estimation of latent demand compared to other countries for which no known data are available. Of the many alternatives, I have found the assumption that the world’s highest aggregate income and highest income-per-capita markets reflect the best standards for “efficiency”. High aggregate income alone is not sufficient (i.e., China has high aggregate income, but low income per capita and can not assumed to be efficient). Aggregate income can be operationalized in a number of ways, including gross domestic product (for industrial categories), or total disposable income (for household categories; population times average income per capita, or number of households times average household income per capita). Brunei, Nauru, Kuwait, and Lichtenstein are examples of countries with high income per capita, but not assumed to be efficient, given low aggregate level of income (or gross domestic product); these countries have, however, high incomes per capita but may not benefit from the efficiencies derived from economies of scale associated with large economies. Only countries with high income per capita and large aggregate income are assumed efficient. This greatly restricts the pool of countries to those in the OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development), like the United States, or the United Kingdom (which were earlier than other large OECD economies to liberalize their markets). The selection of countries is further reduced by the fact that not all countries in the OECD report industry revenues at the category level. Countries that typically have ample data at the aggregate level that meet the efficiency criteria include the United States, the United Kingdom and in some cases France and Germany. Latent demand is therefore estimated using data collected for relatively efficient markets from independent data sources (e.g. Euromonitor, Mintel, Thomson Financial Services, the U.S. Industrial Outlook, the World Resources Institute, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, various agencies from the United Nations, industry trade associations, the International Monetary Fund, and the World Bank). Depending on original data sources used, the definition of “lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels” is established. In the case of this report, the data were reported at the aggregate level, with no further breakdown or definition. In other words, any potential product or service that might be incorporated within lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels falls under this category. Public sources rarely report data at the disaggregated level in order to protect private information from individual firms that might dominate a specific product-market. These sources will therefore aggregate across components of a category and report only the aggregate to the public. While private data are certainly available, this report only relies on public data at the aggregate level without reliance on the summation of various category components. In other words, this report does not aggregate a number of components to arrive at the “whole”. Rather, it starts with the “whole”, and estimates the whole for all countries and the world at large (without needing to know the specific parts that went into the whole in the first place). Given this caveat, this study covers “lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels” as defined by the North American Industrial Classification system or NAICS (pronounced “nakes”). For a complete definition of lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels, please refer to the Web site at http://www.icongrouponline.com/codes/NAICS.html. The NAICS code for lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels is 3231103111. It is for this definition of lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels that the aggregate latent demand estimates are derived. Step 2. Filtering and Smoothing Based on the aggregate view of lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels as defined above, data were then collected for as many similar countries as possible for that same definition, at the same level of the value chain. This generates a convenience sample of countries from which comparable figures are available. If the series in question do not reflect the same accounting period, then adjustments are made. In order to eliminate short-term effects of business cycles, the series are smoothed using an 2 year moving average weighting scheme (longer weighting schemes do not substantially change the results). If data are available for a country, but these reflect short-run aberrations due to exogenous shocks (such as would be the case of beef sales in a country stricken with foot and mouth disease), these observations were dropped or "filtered" from the analysis. Step 3. Filling in Missing Values In some cases, data are available for countries on a sporadic basis. In other cases, data from a country may be available for only one year. From a Bayesian perspective, these observations should be given greatest weight in estimating missing years. Assuming that other factors are held constant, the missing years are extrapolated using changes and growth in aggregate national income. Based on the overriding philosophy of a long-run consumption function (defined earlier), countries which have missing data for any given year, are estimated based on historical dynamics of aggregate income for that country. Step 4. Varying Parameter, Non-linear Estimation Given the data available from the first three steps, the latent demand in additional countries is estimated using a “varying-parameter cross-sectionally pooled time series model”. Simply stated, the effect of income on latent demand is assumed to be constant across countries unless there is empirical evidence to suggest that this effect varies (i.e., . the slope of the income effect is not necessarily same for all countries). This assumption applies across countries along the aggregate consumption function, but also over time (i.e., not all countries are perceived to have the same income growth prospects over time and this effect can vary from country to country as well). Another way of looking at this is to say that latent demand for lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels is more likely to be similar across countries that have similar characteristics in terms of economic development (i.e., African countries will have similar latent demand structures controlling for the income variation across the pool of African countries). This approach is useful across countries for which some notion of non-linearity exists in the aggregate cross-country consumption function. For some categories, however, the reader must realize that the numbers will reflect a country’s contribution to global latent demand and may never be realized in the form of local sales. For certain country-category combinations this will result in what at first glance will be odd results. For example, the latent demand for the category “space vehicles” will exist for “Togo” even though they have no space program. The assumption is that if the economies in these countries did not exist, the world aggregate for these categories would be lower. The share attributed to these countries is based on a proportion of their income (however small) being used to consume the category in question (i.e., perhaps via resellers). Step 5. Fixed-Parameter Linear Estimation Nonlinearities are assumed in cases where filtered data exist along the aggregate consumption function. Because the world consists of more than 200 countries, there will always be those countries, especially toward the bottom of the consumption function, where non-linear estimation is simply not possible. For these countries, equilibrium latent demand is assumed to be perfectly parametric and not a function of wealth (i.e., a country’s stock of income), but a function of current income (a country’s flow of income). In the long run, if a country has no current income, the latent demand for lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels is assumed to approach zero. The assumption is that wealth stocks fall rapidly to zero if flow income falls to zero (i.e., countries which earn low levels of income will not use their savings, in the long run, to demand lithographic printing of flat custom and stock paper labels excluding pressure-sensitive labels). In a graphical sense, for low income countries, latent demand approaches zero in a parametric linear fashion with a zero-zero intercept. In this stage of the estimation procedure, low-income countries are assumed to have a latent demand proportional to their income, based on the country closest to it on the aggregate consumption function. Step 6. Aggregation and Benchmarking Based on the models described above, latent demand figures are estimated for all countries of the world, including for the smallest economies. These are then aggregated to get world totals and regional totals. To make the numbers more meaningful, regional and global demand averages are presented. Figures are rounded, so minor inconsistencies may exist across tables. Step 7. Latent Demand Density: Allocating Across Cities With the advent of a “borderless world”, cities become a more important criteria in prioritizing markets, as opposed to regions, continents, or countries. This report also covers the world’s top 2000 cities. The purpose is to understand the density of demand within a country and the extent to which a city might be used as a point of distribution within its region. From an economic perspective, however, a city does not represent a population within rigid geographical boundaries. To an economist or strategic planner, a city represents an area of dominant influence over markets in adjacent areas. This influence varies from one industry to another, but also from one period of time to another. Similar to country-level data, the reader needs to realize that latent demand allocated to a city may or may not represent real sales. For many items, latent demand is clearly observable in sales, as in the case for food or housing items. Consider, again, the category “satellite launch vehicles.” Clearly, there are no launch pads in most cities of the world. However, the core benefit of the vehicles (e.g. telecommunications, etc.) is "consumed" by residents or industries within the worlds cities. Without certain cities, in other words, the world market for satellite launch vehicles would be lower for the world in general. One needs to allocate, therefore, a portion of the worldwide economic demand for launch vehicles to regions, countries and cities. This report takes the broader definition and considers, therefore, a city as a part of the global market. I allocate latent demand across areas of dominant influence based on the relative economic importance of cities within its home country, within its region and across the world total. Not all cities are estimated within each country as demand may be allocated to adjacent areas of influence. Since some cities have higher economic wealth than others within the same country, a city’s population is not generally used to allocate latent demand. Rather, the level of economic activity of the city vis-à-vis others.
 
Contents:
1 INTRODUCTION 10 1.1 Overview 10 1.2 What is Latent Demand and the P.I.E.? 10 1.3 The Methodology 11 1.3.1 Step 1. Product Definition and Data Collection 12 1.3.2 Step 2. Filtering and Smoothing 13 1.3.3 Step 3. Filling in Missing Values 13 1.3.4 Step 4. Varying Parameter, Non-linear Estimation 14 1.3.5 Step 5. Fixed-Parameter Linear Estimation 14 1.3.6 Step 6. Aggregation and Benchmarking 15 1.3.7 Step 7. Latent Demand Density: Allocating Across Cities 15 2 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS 16 2.1 The Worldwide Market Potential 16 3 AFRICA & THE MIDDLE EAST 18 3.1 Executive Summary 18 3.2 Afghanistan 19 3.3 Algeria 20 3.4 Angola 21 3.5 Armenia 22 3.6 Azerbaijan 23 3.7 Bahrain 24 3.8 Benin 25 3.9 Botswana 25 3.10 Burkina Faso 26 3.11 Burundi 27 3.12 Cameroon 28 3.13 Cape Verde 29 3.14 Central African Republic 29 3.15 Chad 30 3.16 Comoros 31 3.17 Congo (formerly Zaire) 31 3.18 Cote dIvoire 32 3.19 Djibouti 33 3.20 Egypt 34 3.21 Equatorial Guinea 35 3.22 Ethiopia 35 3.23 Gabon 36 3.24 Ghana 37 3.25 Guinea 38 3.26 Guinea-Bissau 38 3.27 Iran 39 3.28 Iraq 40 3.29 Israel 41 3.30 Jordan 42 3.31 Kenya 43 3.32 Kuwait 44 3.33 Kyrgyzstan 44 3.34 Lebanon 45 3.35 Lesotho 46 3.36 Liberia 46 3.37 Libya 47 3.38 Madagascar 48 3.39 Malawi 48 3.40 Mali 49 3.41 Mauritania 50 3.42 Mauritius 50 3.43 Morocco 51 3.44 Mozambique 52 3.45 Namibia 52 3.46 Niger 53 3.47 Nigeria 54 3.48 Oman 55 3.49 Pakistan 55 3.50 Palestine 56 3.51 Qatar 57 3.52 Republic of Congo 57 3.53 Reunion 58 3.54 Rwanda 59 3.55 Sao Tome E Principe 59 3.56 Saudi Arabia 60 3.57 Senegal 61 3.58 Sierra Leone 61 3.59 Somalia 62 3.60 South Africa 63 3.61 Sudan 64 3.62 Swaziland 65 3.63 Syrian Arab Republic 65 3.64 Tajikistan 66 3.65 Tanzania 67 3.66 The Gambia 68 3.67 The United Arab Emirates 69 3.68 Togo 69 3.69 Tunisia 70 3.70 Turkey 71 3.71 Turkmenistan 72 3.72 Uganda 73 3.73 Uzbekistan 74 3.74 Western Sahara 75 3.75 Yemen 75 3.76 Zambia 76 3.77 Zimbabwe 77 4 ASIA 78 4.1 Executive Summary 78 4.2 Bangladesh 79 4.3 Bhutan 80 4.4 Brunei 81 4.5 Burma 82 4.6 Cambodia 83 4.7 China 83 4.8 Hong Kong 84 4.9 India 85 4.10 Indonesia 86 4.11 Japan 87 4.12 Laos 88 4.13 Macau 88 4.14 Malaysia 89 4.15 Maldives 90 4.16 Mongolia 91 4.17 Nepal 91 4.18 North Korea 92 4.19 Papua New Guinea 93 4.20 Philippines 93 4.21 Seychelles 94 4.22 Singapore 95 4.23 South Korea 96 4.24 Sri Lanka 97 4.25 Taiwan 98 4.26 Thailand 99 4.27 Vietnam 100 5 EUROPE 101 5.1 Executive Summary 101 5.2 Albania 102 5.3 Andorra 103 5.4 Austria 104 5.5 Belarus 105 5.6 Belgium 106 5.7 Bosnia and Herzegovina 107 5.8 Bulgaria 107 5.9 Croatia 108 5.10 Cyprus 109 5.11 Czech Republic 110 5.12 Denmark 111 5.13 Estonia 112 5.14 Finland 112 5.15 France 113 5.16 Georgia 114 5.17 Germany 115 5.18 Greece 116 5.19 Hungary 117 5.20 Iceland 118 5.21 Ireland 119 5.22 Italy 119 5.23 Kazakhstan 120 5.24 Latvia 121 5.25 Liechtenstein 122 5.26 Lithuania 123 5.27 Luxembourg 123 5.28 Malta 124 5.29 Moldova 125 5.30 Monaco 125 5.31 Norway 126 5.32 Poland 127 5.33 Portugal 128 5.34 Romania 129 5.35 Russia 130 5.36 San Marino 131 5.37 Slovakia 131 5.38 Slovenia 132 5.39 Spain 133 5.40 Sweden 134 5.41 Switzerland 135 5.42 The Netherlands 136 5.43 The United Kingdom 137 5.44 Ukraine 138 6 LATIN AMERICA 139 6.1 Executive Summary 139 6.2 Argentina 140 6.3 Belize 141 6.4 Bolivia 142 6.5 Brazil 143 6.6 Chile 144 6.7 Colombia 145 6.8 Costa Rica 146 6.9 Ecuador 146 6.10 El Salvador 147 6.11 French Guiana 148 6.12 Guatemala 148 6.13 Guyana 149 6.14 Honduras 150 6.15 Mexico 151 6.16 Nicaragua 152 6.17 Panama 153 6.18 Paraguay 154 6.19 Peru 155 6.20 Suriname 156 6.21 The Falkland Islands 156 6.22 Uruguay 157 6.23 Venezuela 158 7 NORTH AMERICA & THE CARIBBEAN 159 7.1 Executive Summary 159 7.2 Antigua and Barbuda 160 7.3 Aruba 161 7.4 Barbados 162 7.5 Bermuda 162 7.6 Canada 163 7.7 Cuba 164 7.8 Dominica 165 7.9 Dominican Republic 165 7.10 Greenland 166 7.11 Grenada 167 7.12 Guadeloupe 168 7.13 Haiti 169 7.14 Jamaica 169 7.15 Martinique 170 7.16 Puerto Rico 171 7.17 St. Kitts and Nevis 172 7.18 St. Lucia 172 7.19 St. Vincent and the Grenadines 173 7.20 The Bahamas 174 7.21 The British Virgin Islands 174 7.22 The Cayman Islands 175 7.23 The Netherlands Antilles 176 7.24 The U.S. Virgin Islands 176 7.25 The United States 177 7.26 Trinidad and Tobago 178 8 OCEANA 180 8.1 Executive Summary 180 8.2 American Samoa 181 8.3 Australia 182 8.4 Christmas Island 183 8.5 Cook Islands 183 8.6 Fiji 184 8.7 French Polynesia 185 8.8 Guam 185 8.9 Kiribati 186 8.10 Marshall Islands 187 8.11 Micronesia Federation 187 8.12 Nauru 188 8.13 New Caledonia 189 8.14 New Zealand 189 8.15 Niue 190 8.16 Norfolk Island 191 8.17 Palau 191 8.18 Solomon Islands 192 8.19 The Northern Mariana Island 193 8.20 Tokelau 193 8.21 Tonga 194 8.22 Tuvalu 195 8.23 Vanuatu 195 8.24 Wallis and Futuna 196 8.25 Western Samoa 197 9 DISCLAIMERS, WARRANTEES, AND USER AGREEMENT PROVISIONS 198 9.1 Disclaimers & Safe Harbor 198 9.2 ICON Group International, Inc. User Agreement Provisions 199
 
Ordering:
Order Online - visit http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/674489

Order by Fax - using the order form below

Order By Post - print the order form below and send to

Research and Markets,
Guinness Centre,
Taylors Lane,
Dublin 8,
Ireland.

 
Page 1 of 2
Printed Sep 16th 2014
6:02:24 AM

Fax order form

To place a fax order simply print this form, fill in and fax the completed form to the number below. If you have any questions please email help@researchandmarkets.net

Order information

Please verify that the product information is correct and select the format you require.

Product name

The 2009-2014 World Outlook for Lithographic Printing of Flat Custom and Stock Paper Labels Excluding Pressure-Sensitive Labels

Web Address

http://www.researchandmarkets.com/reports/674489

Office Code

OCGOOGLE

 

Report Formats

Please enter the quantity of the report format you require.

Format Quantity Price
Electronic (PDF) - Single User USD 795

Contact information

Please enter all the information below in block capitals.

Title:
Mr Mrs Dr Miss Ms Prof
First Name:
Last Name:
Email Address:
Job Title:
Organisation:
Address:
City:
Postal / Zip Code:
Country:
Phone Number:
Fax Number:

Please fax this form to:
(646) 607-1907 or (646) 964-6609 (from USA)
+353-1-481-1716 or +353-1-653-1571 (from Rest of World)

Page 2 of 2
Printed Sep 16th 2014
6:02:24 AM

Payment information

Please indicate the payment method you would like to use by selecting the appropriate box.

Pay by Credit Card:

American Express

Diners Club

Master Card

Visa

Cardholder's Name:
Cardholder's Signature:
Expiry Date:
/
Card Number:
CVV Security Code:
Issue date:
/ (Diners Club only)
 
Pay by Check:

Please post the check, accompanied by this form, to:

Research and Markets,
Guinness Centre,
Taylors Lane,
Dublin 8,
Ireland.

 
Pay by Wire Transfer:

Please transfer funds to:

Account Number:
83313083
Sort Code:
98-53-30
Swift Code:
ULSBIE2D
IBAN Number:
IE78ULSB98533083313083
Bank Address:
Ulster Bank,
27-35 Main Street
Blackrock,
Co. Dublin
Ireland.
 

If you have a Marketing Code please enter it below:

Marketing Code:

Please note that by ordering from Research and Markets you are agreeing to our Terms and Conditions at http://www.researchandmarkets.com/info/terms.asp

Please fax this form to:
(646) 607-1907 or (646) 964-6609 (from USA)
+353-1-481-1716 or +353-1-653-1571 (from Rest of World)